2015
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2600606
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Federal Programs and the Real Costs of Policing

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

0
6
0
1

Year Published

2015
2015
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
4
2

Relationship

0
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 11 publications
(7 citation statements)
references
References 5 publications
0
6
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…the appropriate portion of overheads) (Local Government Association of South Australia, 2013; Sipilä, 2003). Full-cost pricing is widely applied in public policies and public law-based regulation (Coller & Collini, 2015;Groot & Budding, 2004;Harmon, 2015). Sources: Arrunada (2001) and Ellwood (1996).…”
Section: Problems Relating To Full-cost Pricingmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…the appropriate portion of overheads) (Local Government Association of South Australia, 2013; Sipilä, 2003). Full-cost pricing is widely applied in public policies and public law-based regulation (Coller & Collini, 2015;Groot & Budding, 2004;Harmon, 2015). Sources: Arrunada (2001) and Ellwood (1996).…”
Section: Problems Relating To Full-cost Pricingmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The problem with such an approach, however, is that it ignores the very real tangible and intangible costs of policing, especially to the minority population that is most impacted by its negative consequences. Not surprisingly, this group is often the most politically weak in a community, and has little opportunity to offset the inequities in discussions about policing (Harmon, 2015). Harmon (2015), for example, states that because only a small percentage of the population is searched, arrested, or really has any interaction with the police, there is a “decoupling between the population that experiences the benefits of policing – which are widely distributed – and the population that pays its costs, which are concentrated on a smaller, politically weak minority, including criminal suspects” (p. 941).…”
Section: The Social Costs Of Policingmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Not surprisingly, this group is often the most politically weak in a community, and has little opportunity to offset the inequities in discussions about policing (Harmon, 2015). Harmon (2015), for example, states that because only a small percentage of the population is searched, arrested, or really has any interaction with the police, there is a “decoupling between the population that experiences the benefits of policing – which are widely distributed – and the population that pays its costs, which are concentrated on a smaller, politically weak minority, including criminal suspects” (p. 941). Incorporation of the arrest, incarceration, and collateral costs of a police practice, therefore, will provide a voice to those who have been excluded from decisions surrounding policing programs.…”
Section: The Social Costs Of Policingmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…279 While the creation of collateral incentives may not run afoul of the constitutional rules, it is certainly in tension with the federalist preference to leave the police power to state control. 280 In tension with the incentives set up by Secure Communities, Oregon law, for example, prohibits state law enforcement from using agency "moneys, equipment or personnel for the purpose of detecting or apprehending persons whose only violation of law is that they are persons of foreign citizenship present in the United States in violation of federal immigration laws.…”
Section: Collateral Incentives and The Significance Of Explicit Stmentioning
confidence: 99%