2012
DOI: 10.1140/epjb/e2012-30239-3
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Exploiting the flexibility of a family of models for taxation and redistribution

Abstract: We discuss a family of models expressed by nonlinear differential equation systems describing closed market societies in the presence of taxation and redistribution. We focus in particular on three example models obtained in correspondence to different parameter choices. We analyse the influence of the various choices on the long time shape of the income distribution. Several simulations suggest that behavioral heterogeneity among the individuals plays a definite role in the formation of fat tails of the asymp… Show more

Help me understand this report
View preprint versions

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

2
62
0

Year Published

2014
2014
2017
2017

Publication Types

Select...
4
1

Relationship

2
3

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 30 publications
(64 citation statements)
references
References 20 publications
2
62
0
Order By: Relevance
“…More details on the primary mechanism underlying it can be found in our papers [4,5,6,7,8]. We point out however that in [4,5,6] the phenomenon of tax evasion was not taken into account, whereas in [7,8] all individuals were assumed to engage to the same degree in a kind of evasion different from that dealt with here. 1 The main novelty here is given by the assumption of the existence of different degrees of evasion.…”
Section: The Modelmentioning
confidence: 88%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…More details on the primary mechanism underlying it can be found in our papers [4,5,6,7,8]. We point out however that in [4,5,6] the phenomenon of tax evasion was not taken into account, whereas in [7,8] all individuals were assumed to engage to the same degree in a kind of evasion different from that dealt with here. 1 The main novelty here is given by the assumption of the existence of different degrees of evasion.…”
Section: The Modelmentioning
confidence: 88%
“…-in (6), C (j,α) (j−1,α);(k,β) is defined only for j ≥ 2 and k ≥ 2; -in (4) − (6), the indices α and β take any value in {1, ..., m}. We also emphasize that the coefficients p h,k enter in the formulae (4), (5), (6) in such a way that their effect can be also interpreted as weighting the amount of money exchanged. In other words, the situation is the same one would have assuming the frequency of payment of individuals independent on the income class, but with the amount of money paid in each transaction by individuals of the h-th income class to individuals of the k-th income class equal to p h,k S instead of S. The specific choice of p h,k adopted here is suggested by the phenomenological observation that typically poor people pay and earn less than rich people.…”
Section: Examplementioning
confidence: 99%
“…This is valid for incomes r j which increase linearly, namely r j = j · ∆r (for more general expressions compare Ref. [13,14]). The δ hk appearing here denotes the Kronecker's delta and must be defined for indices which go from 0 to n + 1.…”
Section: A Linear Stochastic Vs Kinetic Modelmentioning
confidence: 95%
“…The fundamental variables are, in this case, the population fractions x i (i = 1, 2, ..., n) of the classes. The interclass interactions are non-linear in these variables and the evolution equations fit into a discretized kinetic framework [13,14].…”
Section: A Linear Stochastic Vs Kinetic Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation