Our system is currently under heavy load due to increased usage. We're actively working on upgrades to improve performance. Thank you for your patience.
2011
DOI: 10.1007/s10797-011-9181-0
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Evidence of the invisible: toward a credibility revolution in the empirical analysis of tax evasion and the informal economy

Abstract: Empirical research about tax evasion and the informal economy has exploded in the past few decades, seeking to shed light on the magnitude and (especially policy) determinants of these phenomena. Quantitative information informs the analysis of policy choices, enables the testing of hypotheses about determinants of this phenomenon, and can help with the accurate construction of national income accounts. Even as empirical analysis has burgeoned, some have expressed doubts about the quality and usefulness of som… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

7
119
0
2

Year Published

2011
2011
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
7
2
1

Relationship

0
10

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 194 publications
(132 citation statements)
references
References 44 publications
(64 reference statements)
7
119
0
2
Order By: Relevance
“…The sign of the elasticity of non-compliance behaviours with respect to the net-of-tax rate is theoretically ambiguous, not just because of income effects, but because the substitution effect can be either positive or negative, depending on the structure of penalties, taxes, and detection probabilities. Empirical studies give mixed results (for recent literature reviews, see Slemrod and Yitzhaki [2002], Slemrod and Stephan [2007], and Slemrod and Weber [2012]), that prove to be very sensitive to the empirical specification, due to the lack of exogenous variation in tax rates. One exception is the study of randomized audits in Denmark by Kleven et al [2011], which exploit kinks created by non-linear tax schedules to estimate the effect of the marginal tax rate on evasion.…”
Section: The Elasticity Of Overreporting Contributionsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The sign of the elasticity of non-compliance behaviours with respect to the net-of-tax rate is theoretically ambiguous, not just because of income effects, but because the substitution effect can be either positive or negative, depending on the structure of penalties, taxes, and detection probabilities. Empirical studies give mixed results (for recent literature reviews, see Slemrod and Yitzhaki [2002], Slemrod and Stephan [2007], and Slemrod and Weber [2012]), that prove to be very sensitive to the empirical specification, due to the lack of exogenous variation in tax rates. One exception is the study of randomized audits in Denmark by Kleven et al [2011], which exploit kinks created by non-linear tax schedules to estimate the effect of the marginal tax rate on evasion.…”
Section: The Elasticity Of Overreporting Contributionsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Second, we estimate our equation with a tobit model, using the full sample. The tobit model is especially suited to censored data and it has been used in other studies in the tax experiments literature, for the same reason that motivates us to adopt it here (Slemrod and Weber 2012;Alm and McClellan 2012;Alm, Cherry, Jones and McKee 2010;Coricelli, Joffily, Montmarquette and Villeval 2007). However, it is particularly sensitive to deviations from the assumptions of normality of the error.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…28 It is important to note that there is no unique definition of the tax gap and therefore, comparisons of measurement results must be made with caution, even Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics, 2016, Vol. 152 (2) 29 Although in theory, the difference between tax non-compliance and tax avoidance is clear, the former is illegal and the latter is legal, in practice, as for example Slemrod and Weber (2012) point out, the distinction between the two is often blurred. 30 The audit program for the tax year 2006 rigorously checked more than 22,000 individual taxpayers and companies selected by a stratified random sampling process (SKAT, 2009a).…”
Section: Tax Gap Estimates By Tax Authoritiesmentioning
confidence: 99%