2004
DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2004.00625.x
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Endogenous Liquidity in Asset Markets

Abstract: This paper analyzes a model in which long-term risky assets are illiquid due to adverse selection. The degree of adverse selection and hence the liquidity of these assets is determined endogenously by the amount of trade for reasons other than private information. I find that higher productivity leads to increased liquidity. Moreover, liquidity magnifies the effects of changes in productivity on investment and volume. High productivity implies that investors initiate larger scale risky projects which increases… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

7
169
0
2

Year Published

2010
2010
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
5
3
1

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 289 publications
(178 citation statements)
references
References 44 publications
(45 reference statements)
7
169
0
2
Order By: Relevance
“…This literature was initiated by Bernanke and Gertler (1989) who show that higher net wealth during booms reduces agency costs, while the lower net wealth during recessions leads to higher agency costs and tighter collateral constraints (see also Eisfeldt (2004)). Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) show in a deterministic model how a temporary productivity shock can lead to a dynamic multiplier.…”
Section: Related Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%
“…This literature was initiated by Bernanke and Gertler (1989) who show that higher net wealth during booms reduces agency costs, while the lower net wealth during recessions leads to higher agency costs and tighter collateral constraints (see also Eisfeldt (2004)). Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) show in a deterministic model how a temporary productivity shock can lead to a dynamic multiplier.…”
Section: Related Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%
“…The result is stated below and proved in the appendix. 18 If the proposed candidate policy is optimal, then it is marginally optimal to invest one unit in the liquid consol at t; roll over dividends into the liquid consol before t n ; and invest only in the illiquid consol after t n : Under such a proposed policy, one unit invested at t grows to e rðsÀtÞ at any time spt n ; becomes 1 1þe e rðt n ÀtÞ shares of the illiquid consols at t n ; and pays off 1Àe 1þe e rðt n ÀtÞ exp½ R 1þe ðs À t n Þ at any time s4t n : Under the alternate policy, however, one unit invested at t becomes, at any time spt n ; 1 1þe shares of the illiquid consol (which pays off 1Àe 1þe ), plus, from the dividends rolled over into the liquid consol between time t and s; 1 1þe R s t Re rðsÀuÞ du: At s4t n ; the total illiquid consol holding is 1 1þe exp½ R 1þe ðs À t n Þ þ R ð1þeÞ 2 r ½e rðt n ÀtÞ À 1 exp½ R 1þe ðs À t n Þ ; which, when multiplied by 1 À e; gives the liquidation revenue at time s4t n : The difference between the two policies gives Eq. (25).…”
Section: Necessary and Sufficient Conditions For The Optimal Policymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…3 See, for example, [2,4,12,21,22,25,[34][35][36]. Also see [1,24], for example, for effect of liquidity on asset prices in the context of asymmetric information, and see [18] for a model with endogenous liquidity correlated with productivity and investment.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In particular extremely favourable industrial production and unemployment news lead to a significant increase in Pr ( 0) it r = . Given the pro-cyclicality of stock market liquidity (see Eisfeldt, 2004), our results suggest that bond and stock market liquidity should be seen as substitutes rather than as complements over the business cycle. …”
Section: -Commonality Across Government Bonds In Europementioning
confidence: 99%