2005
DOI: 10.1111/j.1467-8489.2005.00295.x
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Economic substitution for US wheat food use by class*

Abstract: Wheat for food use is conceptualised as an input into flour production and demand is derived from an industry profit function to quantify price responsiveness and economic substitutability across wheat classes. Price and substitution elasticities are estimated for hard red winter, hard red spring, soft red wheat, soft white winter and durum wheat. In general, hard red winter and spring wheat varieties are much more responsive to their own price than are soft wheat varieties and durum wheat. Substitution elasti… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1

Citation Types

3
13
0

Year Published

2006
2006
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
7

Relationship

2
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 10 publications
(16 citation statements)
references
References 22 publications
(26 reference statements)
3
13
0
Order By: Relevance
“…11 Data on prices and quantities were collected for a recent year (2002) and the parameters of the linear demand and supply functions (equations (3)-(5)) were calibrated using the method introduced by Dixit (1988). In terms of the benchmark calibration, we used the following values: the domestic demand elasticity equal to −0.8 (this accords with empirical studies of the cereals market published by Marsh (2005) for the Alston and Gray (2000) in their study of the CWB; and the elasticity of substitution was initially set at 3, capturing some limited degree of substitution between wheat from different sources. 12 Clearly, in some empirical studies different values for these elasticities have been found so we conducted sensitivity analysis by varying each of these parameters.…”
Section: Consumer Tax and Export Subsidy Equivalent Effectsmentioning
confidence: 98%
“…11 Data on prices and quantities were collected for a recent year (2002) and the parameters of the linear demand and supply functions (equations (3)-(5)) were calibrated using the method introduced by Dixit (1988). In terms of the benchmark calibration, we used the following values: the domestic demand elasticity equal to −0.8 (this accords with empirical studies of the cereals market published by Marsh (2005) for the Alston and Gray (2000) in their study of the CWB; and the elasticity of substitution was initially set at 3, capturing some limited degree of substitution between wheat from different sources. 12 Clearly, in some empirical studies different values for these elasticities have been found so we conducted sensitivity analysis by varying each of these parameters.…”
Section: Consumer Tax and Export Subsidy Equivalent Effectsmentioning
confidence: 98%
“…Malting barley maintains a sensitive product quality structure, and much of what is planted for malting markets ends up as lower-priced feed barley. There exists a convincing and growing literature that suggests that a more differentiated market exists for most of the internationally traded grains that go beyond the standard grading system, e.g., Stiegert and Blanc (1997) ;Johnson, Grennes, and Thursby (1979);and Marsh (2005). In most cases, raw food commodities are differentiated by quality attributes, physical growing constraints, geographic origin, credit policies, delivery dates, and ancillary services.…”
mentioning
confidence: 98%
“… See Marsh (2005) for an in‐depth literature review of studies, which focused on the wheat market. …”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Free Trade Agreement (CUSTA) are some of the factors cited which have encouraged U.S.‐Canada trade. Please see Koo and Mattson (2002) and Johnson and Wilson (2005) for details.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation