2006
DOI: 10.1111/j.1756-2171.2006.tb00063.x
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Dynamic monopoly pricing and herding

Abstract: We study dynamic pricing by a monopolist selling to buyers who learn from each other's purchases. The price posted in each period serves to extract rent from the current buyer, as well as to control the amount of information transmitted to future buyers. As information increases future rent extraction, the monopolist has an incentive to subsidize learning by charging a price that results in information revelation. Nonetheless, in the long run, the monopolist generally induces herding by either selling to all b… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

3
61
0

Year Published

2007
2007
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 70 publications
(64 citation statements)
references
References 23 publications
3
61
0
Order By: Relevance
“…13 Bose et al (2005aBose et al ( , 2005b) also find convexity of profits, in their case in the prior belief. Thus the firm, which does not know its own product quality, will want to release information -setting a high price to early customers reveals information about their private signals, moving the prior up or down, while at a low price everybody buys so nothing is revealed.…”
Section: Optimality Of Extreme Reviewersmentioning
confidence: 96%
“…13 Bose et al (2005aBose et al ( , 2005b) also find convexity of profits, in their case in the prior belief. Thus the firm, which does not know its own product quality, will want to release information -setting a high price to early customers reveals information about their private signals, moving the prior up or down, while at a low price everybody buys so nothing is revealed.…”
Section: Optimality Of Extreme Reviewersmentioning
confidence: 96%
“…We note that the beneficial effects of SL on expected profit when the firm adjusts prices dynamically have been established previously in the literature, but under the assumption that consumers are non-strategic (e.g., Bose et al 2006, Ifrach et al 2013). Proposition 8 generalizes this finding to the case of forward-looking consumers.…”
Section: First-period Pricing and Purchasing Strategiesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Notice that when γ = 0, the SL process is essentially inactive: the updated belief,q u , is identical to the prior belief,q p . This case reflects situations in which SL is either (i) irrelevant, because there is no ex ante quality uncertainty (i.e., σ p → 0) and therefore nothing to be learned from product reviews, 4 Since the firm and consumers hold the same prior belief, firm actions in our model cannot convey any additional information on product quality to the consumers (i.e., there is no scope for signalling); this informational structure is commonly assumed in the SL literature to focus attention on the peer-to-peer learning process (e.g., Bergemann and Välimäki 1997, Bose et al 2006, Bose et al 2008, YU et al 2013b). Furthermore, although we do not model expert/critic reviews explicitly, these may take part in forming the public prior belief; Dellarocas et al (2007) find that there is generally little overlap between the informational content of critic reviews and that of consumer reviews.…”
Section: Model Descriptionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Bose, Orosel, Ottaviani, and Vesterlund (2006) consider a variation of the classic Bayesian model of social learning when a monopolist and agents are equally uninformed about the value of the good. The monopolist can change the price dynamically to extract revenue and to control the accumulation of information.…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%