ERWP 2015
DOI: 10.24148/wp2013-28
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Doubts and Variability: A Robust Perspective on Exotic Consumption Series

Abstract: Consumption-based asset-pricing models have experienced success in recent years by augmenting the consumption process in 'exotic' ways. Two notable examples are the Long-Run Risk and rare disaster frameworks. Such models are difficult to characterize from consumption data alone. Accordingly, concerns have been raised regarding their specification. Acknowledging that both phenomena are naturally subject to ambiguity, we show that an ambiguity-averse agent may behave as if Long-Run Risk and disasters exist even … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

1
17
0

Year Published

2015
2015
2017
2017

Publication Types

Select...
5

Relationship

0
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 10 publications
(18 citation statements)
references
References 35 publications
1
17
0
Order By: Relevance
“…While it is difficult to determine what the true value for the default frequency is in the data, it seems to be consensus in the literature that it lies close to 3 percent per year (see footnote 7). These papers and ours replicate this feature of the bond spreads in a general equilib-49 To explain different asset-pricing puzzles, Maenhout (2004), Drechsler (2012), and Bidder and Smith (2013) require a detection error probability in the range between 10 and 12 percent. Barillas, Hansen and Sargent (2009) needs even lower values to reach the Hansen and Jagannathan (1991) bounds.…”
Section: B Simulation Resultssupporting
confidence: 64%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…While it is difficult to determine what the true value for the default frequency is in the data, it seems to be consensus in the literature that it lies close to 3 percent per year (see footnote 7). These papers and ours replicate this feature of the bond spreads in a general equilib-49 To explain different asset-pricing puzzles, Maenhout (2004), Drechsler (2012), and Bidder and Smith (2013) require a detection error probability in the range between 10 and 12 percent. Barillas, Hansen and Sargent (2009) needs even lower values to reach the Hansen and Jagannathan (1991) bounds.…”
Section: B Simulation Resultssupporting
confidence: 64%
“…57 56 The weight of one-half is arbitrary; see Barillas, Hansen and Sargent (2009) among others. Moreover, as the number of observations increases, the weight becomes less relevant, since the quantities p A,T and p D,T get closer to each other; as shown in Figure 4 57 To make our results for the DEP comparable with those of Barillas, Hansen andSargent (2009) andBidder andSmith (2013), we consider a similar number of periods and thereby T=240 is chosen. If instead T was set to replicate the number of periods used in the calibration, the DEP would be considerably higher for the same probability distortions.…”
Section: A Detection Error Probabilitiesmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Following Pettenuzzo, Timmermann, and Valkanov (2014), the nonnegativity restriction can 4 Allowing for potential model misspecification could be a natural response of investors to evidence in the literature against certain assumptions or implications of an asset pricing model (e.g., Beeler and Campbell 2012;Yu 2012;Bidder and Smith 2015). 5 We examine versions of the VARs that are estimated without a nonnegativity constraint in the Online Appendix.…”
Section: Predictive Vector Autoregression Estimation Approachmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…She notes that conventional calibrations of the long-run risks model explain a substantially lower fraction of variation in expected returns ( r 2 less than 0.05) and that an estimated version of the model generates even less. Her analysis is based on estimates of a simplified version of the long-run risks model by Bidder and Smith (2015) in which the r 2 of the return predictability regression for the estimated version of the long-run risks model is essentially zero. Our model shows that, in fact, a fully estimated version of the long-run risks model generates more rather than less return predictability than in the calibrations of BY and BKY.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%