2013
DOI: 10.1016/j.wre.2013.07.001
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Distributional considerations of international water resources under externality: The case of Ethiopia, Sudan and Egypt on the Blue Nile

Abstract: copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and education use, including for instruction at the authors institution and sharing with colleagues. Other uses, including reproduction and distribution, or selling or licensing copies, or posting to personal, institutional or third party websites are prohibited. In most cases authors are permitted to post their version of the article (e.g. in Word or Tex form) to their personal website or institutional repository. Authors requiring further i… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

1
24
0

Year Published

2014
2014
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
6
3

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 44 publications
(25 citation statements)
references
References 38 publications
1
24
0
Order By: Relevance
“…The Shapley value prescribes a payoff to each player that is the average marginal worth of that player to all the coalitions in which he or she can participate (Shapley 1953). This method satisfies the Core conditions, namely individual rationality, group rationality, and efficiency (Dinar and Nigatu 2013).…”
Section: Shapley Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…The Shapley value prescribes a payoff to each player that is the average marginal worth of that player to all the coalitions in which he or she can participate (Shapley 1953). This method satisfies the Core conditions, namely individual rationality, group rationality, and efficiency (Dinar and Nigatu 2013).…”
Section: Shapley Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…(Dinar et al 1992;McCarthy et al 2001;Pande and McKee 2007;Dinar and Nigatu 2013;Pande and Ertsen 2014). Some researchers argue that non-cooperative game theory solutions lead to overexploitation of the shared water resources and they are typically inefficient (Ambec and Ehlers 2008), whereas some others believe that there are some reasons for the players to prefer non-cooperation (Dinar and Nigatu 2013), for instance, high coordination cost associated with cooperation of large numbers of players (Just and Netanyahu 1998) or historical and cultural disputes among states. Recent literature on cooperative game theory distinguishes between games with transferable utility and games with non-transferable utility (Dinar et al 1992).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In some river basins, countries may prefer to allocate physical units of water (cf. Dinar and Nigatu, 2013), while in other basins countries may prefer to allocate the welfare derived from water use (i.e. 'benefit sharing'), although essentially there is not much difference between the two.…”
Section: Fairnessmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The SV and other CGT solutions have often been applied to different aspects of water resource management, such as sharing benefits from groundwater (Madani and Dinar 2012), international rivers (Dinar and Nigatu 2013), wastewater treatment plans (Loehman et al 1979) and regional water supply (Young et al 1982), including application to networks (Dong et al 2012). However, most of these studies include illustrative examples that only consider a limited number of players (typically from 3 to 5) since CGT solutions are notoriously difficult to apply to larger systems.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%