2019
DOI: 10.1038/s41598-019-44184-5
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Dissimilarity-driven behavior and cooperation in the spatial public goods game

Abstract: In this paper, we explore the impact of four different types of dissimilarity-driven behavior on the evolution of cooperation in the spatial public goods game. While it is commonly assumed that individuals adapt their strategy by imitating one of their more successful neighbors, in reality only very few will be awarded the highest payoffs. Many have equity or equality preferences, and they have to make do with an average or even with a low payoff. To account for this, we divide the population into two categori… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
4
1

Citation Types

0
8
0

Year Published

2020
2020
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
6
3

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 24 publications
(8 citation statements)
references
References 72 publications
(50 reference statements)
0
8
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Here we consider the usual imitative rule [51], the Ising (or Glauber dynamics) rule [68], and the dynamic win-stay-loseshift (WSLS) rule [69]. This is done so we can study the robustness of the effects created by payoff perturbation, since previous works have extensively shown how the update rules can lead to different behaviors [22,34,35,47,70,71].…”
Section: Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Here we consider the usual imitative rule [51], the Ising (or Glauber dynamics) rule [68], and the dynamic win-stay-loseshift (WSLS) rule [69]. This is done so we can study the robustness of the effects created by payoff perturbation, since previous works have extensively shown how the update rules can lead to different behaviors [22,34,35,47,70,71].…”
Section: Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…One way to study the influence of such random variations is to represent each different environmental condition as a new factor in the equations of a model. Following this method, many authors have made important advances in the understanding of how a number of conditions can drive the system dynamics, such as resource heterogeneity [46], different behaviors [47,48], seasonal variations [33], diverse learning rates [49], different death rates [50], interaction topologies [51], and so on. However, another way to understand these phenomena is to study the behavior of a population whose evolution can be affected by a payoff matrix constantly perturbed by stochastic noise with zero mean value [52][53][54], regardless of its origin.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…However, if mechanisms like spatial structure are present, cooperators may have a chance depending on the cost to benefit ratio of participating in the PGG [12][13][14][15][16]. Besides spatial structure, that gives rise to network reciprocity, other major mechanisms that help cooperation are the punishment of defectors, the rewarding of cooperators and the ability to not participate in the game [17][18][19][20][21][22][23][24][25][26][27][28]. In spatial PGG, cooperation can thrive if the multiplicative factor is high enough.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…One way to study the influence of such random variations is to represent each different environmental condition as a new factor in the equations of a model. Following this method, many authors have done important advances in the understanding of how a number of conditions can drive the system dynamics, such as resource heterogeneity [40], different behaviours [41,42], seasonal variations [29], diverse learning rates [43], different death rates [44], interaction topologies [45], and so on. However, another way to understand these phenomena is to study the behaviour of a population whose evolution can be affected by a payoff matrix constantly perturbed by stochastic noise with zero mean value [46][47][48], irregardless of its origin.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%