2012
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2010640
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Deficits, Public Debt Dynamics, and Tax and Spending Multipliers

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

7
67
0
1

Year Published

2013
2013
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
5
2

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 44 publications
(75 citation statements)
references
References 15 publications
7
67
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…Using the loglinearized equilibrium conditions produces results that are close to the results reported in Denes, Eggertsson, and Gilbukh (2013). The tax multiplier using our calibration is 0.11 as compared to their value of 0.1 and the government purchase multiplier using our calibration is 1.0,8 as compared to their value of 1.2.…”
Section: Ad and As As Slope(ad)<0supporting
confidence: 78%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…Using the loglinearized equilibrium conditions produces results that are close to the results reported in Denes, Eggertsson, and Gilbukh (2013). The tax multiplier using our calibration is 0.11 as compared to their value of 0.1 and the government purchase multiplier using our calibration is 1.0,8 as compared to their value of 1.2.…”
Section: Ad and As As Slope(ad)<0supporting
confidence: 78%
“…A disturbing aspect of our results is that the asymptote occurs at a value of p that is close to values maintained in previous research. Denes, Eggertsson, and Gilbukh (2013) To the right of the asymptote, the targeted nonlinear equilibrium has the property that slope(AS) > slope(AD) > 0 and it follows immediately from Proposition 5 that the sign of the labor tax multiplier must be negative. The loglinearized solution is consistent with this In Section 3.1, we discussed the possibility of multiple equilibria and sunspot equilibria when the loglinearized solution is a Type 2 equilibrium.…”
Section: Our Resultsmentioning
confidence: 97%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…For instance, the long run multiplier is close to unity when debt is low (strong …scal position), but is negative for high levels of debt (weak …scal position). 16 The di¤erence in the estimated multipliers for low and high levels of debt is particularly signi…cant at longer horizons. Our empirical results therefore lend support to the theoretical insights of earlier studies which show that a weak …scal position can result in stronger crowding-out e¤ects, blunting the stimulative e¤ects of …scal policy (Sutherland 1997; Perroti 1999; Corsetti et al 2013; Bi, Shen, and Yang 2014).…”
Section: Unconditional Multipliersmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Apart from an arugment by Easterly et al (2008), which is more relevant for developing countries, there are recent theoretical papers by Denes et al (2012) and DeLong and Summers (2012), which show that such an effect could occur if the interest rate were close to zero. These findings are therefore not applicable to peripheral European countries, which face funding difficulties and rising interest costs.…”
Section: Ecb Working Paper 1697 July 2014mentioning
confidence: 99%