2009
DOI: 10.1093/esr/jcp031
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Curricular Choice: A Test of a Rational Choice Model of Education

Abstract: Rational choice theories of education view student's educational decision as a sequence of binary choices between options that entail long-term utility and options that reduce short-term risk of failure. One of the best articulated models of educational choice asserts that choice between alternative options is affected by students' utility considerations, their expectations regarding the odds of success or failure in alternative educational options, and their motivation to avoid downward social mobility. We ev… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

4
78
0
2

Year Published

2010
2010
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
5
3

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 62 publications
(84 citation statements)
references
References 36 publications
4
78
0
2
Order By: Relevance
“…Quite the contrary, the 'explanatory' hierarchy established on the basis of the dissimilarity index reduction is very much in line with statistically based empirical studies on educational inequalities which suggest that, while ability/cognitive skills systematically exhibit very high predictive power (see, for instance, Gabay-Egozi et al, 2010;Stocke´, 2007), peer effects, when statistically significant, tend to be relatively weak (for an overall assessment, see, for instance, Breen & Jonsson, 2005, p. 229). In this respect, the main contribution of the present simulation-based study is its demonstration that, although their quantitatively average net effect might be modest, dyadic social interactions should not be discarded on a theoretical level because, without them, the actual level of educational inequality could not be accounted for.…”
Section: Discussionsupporting
confidence: 70%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…Quite the contrary, the 'explanatory' hierarchy established on the basis of the dissimilarity index reduction is very much in line with statistically based empirical studies on educational inequalities which suggest that, while ability/cognitive skills systematically exhibit very high predictive power (see, for instance, Gabay-Egozi et al, 2010;Stocke´, 2007), peer effects, when statistically significant, tend to be relatively weak (for an overall assessment, see, for instance, Breen & Jonsson, 2005, p. 229). In this respect, the main contribution of the present simulation-based study is its demonstration that, although their quantitatively average net effect might be modest, dyadic social interactions should not be discarded on a theoretical level because, without them, the actual level of educational inequality could not be accounted for.…”
Section: Discussionsupporting
confidence: 70%
“…From an empirical point of view, while still unclear the extent to which the social differentiation of education benefits is due to status-maintenance concerns, as Breen and Goldthorpe (1997) assume, and how intensely these concerns and cost perceptions only drive secondary effects (see Gabay-Egozi et al, 2010, andStocke´, 2007), it is empirically proven that both benefit and cost subjective perceptions of education tend to be more favourable, the higher the group to which the agent belongs (see, for instance, Becker, 2003, pp. 19-21;Need & de Jong, 2000, p. 88;Stocke´, 2007, p. 512).…”
Section: The Benefit Term (B)mentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…In one of its first applications to motivation in a working environment context, Georgopoulos et al (1957) suggest that individual productivity depends on the degree to which one sees productivity as being instrumental for the achievement of personal goals. Over the past few decades, instrumentality theory and related theories have been applied to many different research questions in educational and occupational contexts-for example, in psychological research on attitudes/preferences (Ajzen and Fishbein 1980), role behavior (Kinicki 1989), goal setting and commitment in the work-space (Lawler and Suttle 1973), job performance (Galbraith and Cummings 1967), occupational choice and turnover (Osborn 1990;Berger and D'Ascoli 2012), job satisfaction and training transfer (Jodlbauer et al 2011;Gegenfurtner 2013), learning intentions (Kyndt et al 2011), and students' study decisions (Gabay-Egozi et al 2010).…”
Section: Theory and Hypothesesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…One strand of research directly estimates the theoretical parameters governing the model of relative risk aversion by Breen and Goldthorpe (1997) (Becker, 2003;Becker & Hecken, 2009;Breen & Yaish, 2006;Gabay-Egozi, Shavit, & Yaish, 2010;Holm & Jaeger, 2008;Jacob & Weiss, 2011;Jaeger & Holm, 2012;Need & de Jong, 2001;Stocké, 2007;van de Werfhorst & Hofstede, 2007), while another strand indirectly infers the relative importance of secondary effects over primary effects from observed correlations between social class, educational decisions, and academic ability or performance (Becker, 2009;Boado, 2011;Contini & Scagni, 2011;Davies, Heinesen, & Holm, 2002;Erikson, 2007;Erikson et al, 2005;Erikson & Rudolphi, 2010;Jackson, 2010Jackson, , 2013Jackson et al, 2007;Kloosterman et al, 2009;Neugebauer, 2010;Neugebauer & Schindler, 2012;Schindler & Lörz, 2012;Schindler & Reimer, 2010). In analyses using discrete measures of social class, this latter strand of research is characterized by producing a plethora of parameters, complicating comparisons across birth cohorts or countries or both.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%