2009
DOI: 10.1257/jep.23.2.99
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Consumer Shopping Behavior: How Much Do Consumers Save?

Abstract: This paper documents the potential and actual savings that consumers realize from four particular types of purchasing behavior: purchasing on sale; buying in bulk (at a lower per unit price); buying generic brands; and choosing outlets. How much can and do households save through each of these behaviors? How do these patterns vary with consumer demographics? We use data collected by a marketing firm on all food purchases brought into the home for a large, nationally representative sample of U.K. households in … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1

Citation Types

3
81
0
1

Year Published

2010
2010
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
4
2
1

Relationship

2
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 121 publications
(85 citation statements)
references
References 16 publications
3
81
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…A recent study by Stroebel and Vavra (2015) also show a correlation between house prices and shopping activities. 9 An alternative approach, used by Griffith et al (2009), is to regress transaction-level prices, rather than a monthly price index, on the shopping activity. The theory we present below is that of an aggregated…”
Section: Change In the Returns To Shoppingmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…A recent study by Stroebel and Vavra (2015) also show a correlation between house prices and shopping activities. 9 An alternative approach, used by Griffith et al (2009), is to regress transaction-level prices, rather than a monthly price index, on the shopping activity. The theory we present below is that of an aggregated…”
Section: Change In the Returns To Shoppingmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For instance, Shapiro and Wilcox (1996) and the Boskin Commission report (1996) show that store-substitution can cause biases in the measurement of consumer inflation, while Griffith et al (2009) documents the reduction in effective prices paid from a range of shopping activities which may not be fully reflected in a fixed-weight inflation index. More recently, studies such as Chevalier andKashyap (2011) andCoibion, Gorodnichenko andHong (2012) show that the gap between effective prices paid and posted prices can vary over time as households change their shopping effort.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…41 The distribution of this random effect has the following properties: (A.1) it has a discrete and finite support Each market type  has its own equilibrium mapping (with a different level of profits given   ) and its own equilibrium. Let P  be a vector of strategies (CCPs) in market-type : P  ≡ {  (x  ) : 42 It is straightforward to extend the description of an equilibrium mapping in CCPs to this model. A vector of CCPs P  is a MPE for market type  if and only if for every firm  and every state x  we have that: Let  be the vector of parameters in the probability mass function of , i.e., ≡ {  :  = 1 2  }, and let P be the set of CCPs for every market type, {P  :  = 1 2  }.…”
Section: Dealing With Unobserved Heterogeneitymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This is the so called initial conditions problem (Heckman, 1981). In short panels (for  relatively small), not 42 The introduction of unobserved market heterogeneity also implies that we can relax the assumption of only 'a single equilibrium in the data' to allow for different market types to have different equilibria. taking into account this dependence between   and x 1 can generate significant biases, similar to the biases associated to ignoring the existence of unobserved market heterogeneity.…”
Section: Dealing With Unobserved Heterogeneitymentioning
confidence: 99%