2020
DOI: 10.1016/j.jmateco.2020.05.010
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Comparative statics for size-dependent discounts in matching markets

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1

Citation Types

0
3
0

Year Published

2020
2020
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
3
1

Relationship

1
3

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 4 publications
(3 citation statements)
references
References 26 publications
0
3
0
Order By: Relevance
“…By contrast, if f interferes, then some of the capacity it is using could be claimed by a higher-priority family. Interference-free matchings may be wasteful, which unfortunately is unavoidable due to a stark trade-off in matching markets with sizes between respecting priorities and eliminating waste-as Delacrétaz (2019) showed, if waste must be eliminated, then one cannot put any bound on the number of units that a family could claim at a more preferred locality. Moreover, the underuse of capacity may well be tolerable in the refugee resettlement context because it can be used for the next cohort of resettled refugee families.…”
Section: A Interference-free Matchingsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…By contrast, if f interferes, then some of the capacity it is using could be claimed by a higher-priority family. Interference-free matchings may be wasteful, which unfortunately is unavoidable due to a stark trade-off in matching markets with sizes between respecting priorities and eliminating waste-as Delacrétaz (2019) showed, if waste must be eliminated, then one cannot put any bound on the number of units that a family could claim at a more preferred locality. Moreover, the underuse of capacity may well be tolerable in the refugee resettlement context because it can be used for the next cohort of resettled refugee families.…”
Section: A Interference-free Matchingsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…2 See Vickrey (1961) for participation costs, Spenner and Freeman (2012) for attracting participants, Pathak and Sönmez (2008) for leveling the playing field, and Wilson (1987) and Bergemann and Morris (2005) for a designer's informational requirements. 3 Examples include auctions (Vickrey (1961), Riley and Samuelson (1981), Myerson (1981)), voting (Arrow (1963)), school choice (Abdulkadiroglu and Sönmez (2003)), organ exchange (Roth, Sönmez, and Ünver (2004)), course allocation (Sönmez and Ünver (2010), Budish and Cantillon (2012)), and refugee resettlement (Jones and Teytelboym (2016), Delacrétaz, Kominers, and Teytelboym (2016)). 4 Direct mechanisms are not necessarily simple, and hence the revelation principle does not extend to simple extensive-form games; cf.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…A small number of papers discuss market design for other development challenges. Many of these expect government to be the main buyer, for example, incentives for vaccines (Kremer, 2001b,a), refugee allocation (Delacrétaz et al, 2020), and antiquity protection (Kremer and Wilkening, 2015). Closer to our motivation, Hussam et al (2022) explore how revelation mechanisms might be used to select quality borrowers.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%