2011
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1973864
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Climate Risks and Carbon Prices: Revising the Social Cost of Carbon

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

1
60
0

Year Published

2011
2011
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
7
2

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 62 publications
(61 citation statements)
references
References 16 publications
1
60
0
Order By: Relevance
“…For instance, we estimate that California would need to value carbon at $160/ton CO 2 to make the current PV incentive for educational institutions pay off (compared to the roughly $40/ton CO 2 that we used in the rest of this paper). It is worth noting that it is not difficult to find literature arguing that CO 2 emissions should be valued at more than $160/ton [58][59][60]. Alternatively, California would need to provide incentives of $350 kW −1 to meet carbon offsets currently valued at $40/ton CO 2 (compared to the current average incentive value of $1400 kW −1 in the LBNL TTS10 dataset [15]).…”
Section: Social Net-benefits Of Us School Pv To the Publicmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For instance, we estimate that California would need to value carbon at $160/ton CO 2 to make the current PV incentive for educational institutions pay off (compared to the roughly $40/ton CO 2 that we used in the rest of this paper). It is worth noting that it is not difficult to find literature arguing that CO 2 emissions should be valued at more than $160/ton [58][59][60]. Alternatively, California would need to provide incentives of $350 kW −1 to meet carbon offsets currently valued at $40/ton CO 2 (compared to the current average incentive value of $1400 kW −1 in the LBNL TTS10 dataset [15]).…”
Section: Social Net-benefits Of Us School Pv To the Publicmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The standard economic formula for this is as a percentage loss of global GDP caused by the contemporaneous level of mean global warming (though whether to use market or purchasing power exchange rates in aggregating global GDP is itself an ethical choice). Disputes solely about such damage functions can readily result in a three‐ to fourfold range of SCCs (e.g., see Figures 4–5 of Ackerman & Stanton, ); though it is also highly questionable whether the standard formula includes all the main causes or effects of warming damage, as noted later. I now discuss three main problems with any damage function: the implicit implausibility to climate scientists of many IAMs' damage functions (illustrated next for DICE, a leading IAM); wide‐ranging criticisms by many economists of the arbitrary guesses found in all damage functions; and the untestability, I will argue, of any “improvements” in damage functions made by future research.…”
Section: The Scc: Unresolvable or Improvable?mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Carbon that is sequestered (added to soil and vegetation, typically measured on an annual basis as tons of carbon per acre per year) or stored (in vegetation and soils in tons of carbon per acre) can be valued by using carbon markets or estimates of the social cost of carbon (Tol, 2008;Ackerman and Stanton, 2012). Given the immature state of carbon markets and the fact that market caps are not tied to ecological thresholds for climate change, market prices are less appropriate than the social cost of carbon in estimating the value of carbon sequestration and storage.…”
Section: Carbonmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…To value carbon storage, we used a set of conservative valuation assumptions ($22/ton social cost of carbon (2011 United States dollars), 7 percent discount rate, 0 percent rate of annual change in the value of carbon, median values from Tol's (2005Tol's ( , 2008) meta-analyses) and a set of nonconservative valuation assumptions ($89/ton social cost of carbon, 1 percent discount rate, 6 percent annual change in the value of carbon, for the most part based on Stern, 2007). The value of carbon and the assumptions that go into these estimates are debated in the literature, and even high values may underestimate the social cost of carbon (Ackerman and Stanton, 2012). However, these estimates do provide defensible high and low values.…”
Section: Follow-up Studiesmentioning
confidence: 99%