2013
DOI: 10.1007/s10640-013-9654-y
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Climate Policy Under Fat-Tailed Risk: An Application of Dice

Abstract: Uncertainty plays a significant role in evaluating climate policy, and fat-tailed uncertainty may dominate policy advice. Should we make our utmost effort to prevent the arbitrarily large impacts of climate change under deep uncertainty? In order to answer to this question, we propose a new way of investigating the impact of (fat-tailed) uncertainty on optimal climate policy: the curvature of the optimal carbon tax against the uncertainty. We find that the optimal carbon tax increases as the uncertainty about … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
13
0

Year Published

2017
2017
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
9

Relationship

1
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 27 publications
(14 citation statements)
references
References 43 publications
0
13
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Many papers expand the DICE framework to investigate the impact of particular aspects of the climate-economy system on the optimal timing of climate mitigation. Examples include Kolstad (1996) and Keller et al (2004) on learning that reduces climate uncertainty over time; Bruin et al (2009) and Bosello et al (2010) on how considering adaptation to climate change impacts may affect optimal mitigation; Hwang et al (2013) and Lemoine and Traeger (2014) on the impact of fat-tailed risks and the role of tipping points; and Heal and Millner (2014) on the choice of the appropriate discount rate for climate policy. Dietz and Stern (2014) propose several modifications to DICE, including the use of a lower discount rate, and a different modelling of climate-change-related damages.…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Many papers expand the DICE framework to investigate the impact of particular aspects of the climate-economy system on the optimal timing of climate mitigation. Examples include Kolstad (1996) and Keller et al (2004) on learning that reduces climate uncertainty over time; Bruin et al (2009) and Bosello et al (2010) on how considering adaptation to climate change impacts may affect optimal mitigation; Hwang et al (2013) and Lemoine and Traeger (2014) on the impact of fat-tailed risks and the role of tipping points; and Heal and Millner (2014) on the choice of the appropriate discount rate for climate policy. Dietz and Stern (2014) propose several modifications to DICE, including the use of a lower discount rate, and a different modelling of climate-change-related damages.…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The law of motion given by equation (12) is different from the one specified by AABH. This is to facilitate the common assumption in integrated assessment models that the rate of CO 2 depreciation in the atmosphere is increasing in the stock of CO 2 ; see, for example, Hwang et al (2013), who use a simplified version of the DICE model. See Appendix A5 for further discussion of this issue and for some other details about the numerical model.…”
Section: Consumers and The Environmentmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…We defer the application of a flexible savings rate to future research. 7 As Hwang et al (2013;2016) show, the application of fat-tailed distribution of the climate sensitivity with CRRA utility function into the DICE model (as in our model) may lead to a catastrophic consumption loss. It would be optimal for the decision maker to reduce carbon emissions totally (i.e.…”
Section: The Revised Dice Modelmentioning
confidence: 86%