2018
DOI: 10.1080/13504851.2018.1488040
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Bitcoin price and its marginal cost of production: support for a fundamental value

Abstract: This study back-tests a marginal cost of production model proposed to value the digital currency bitcoin. Results from both conventional regression and vector autoregression (VAR) models show that the marginal cost of production plays an important role in explaining bitcoin prices, challenging recent allegations that bitcoins are essentially worthless. Even with markets pricing bitcoin in the thousands of dollars each, the valuation model seems robust. The data show that a price bubble that began in the Fall o… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

1
55
3
1

Year Published

2018
2018
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
7
2

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 101 publications
(71 citation statements)
references
References 18 publications
(19 reference statements)
1
55
3
1
Order By: Relevance
“…This result is different from the one obtained by Hayes (2019) and Abbatemarco et al (2018), who conclude that the Bitcoin price could be explained by the cost of production model.…”
Section: Discussioncontrasting
confidence: 93%
“…This result is different from the one obtained by Hayes (2019) and Abbatemarco et al (2018), who conclude that the Bitcoin price could be explained by the cost of production model.…”
Section: Discussioncontrasting
confidence: 93%
“…He argues for a fundamental value given the cost of mining. Similarly, Hayes (2015Hayes ( , 2018 proposed a specific cost of production model for valuating Bitcoin. Additionally, Cheah and Fry (2015) conclude that Bitcoin is a speculative bubble and that the fundamental value of Bitcoin is zero.…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…It is broadly accepted that the probability of finding a valid block-the "arrival rate" of valid blocks-is a Poisson process (Bowden, Keeler, Krzesinski, & Taylor, 2018). This is assumed by authors including Nakamoto (2008), Rosenfeld (2011), Eyal and Sirer (2013), Decker and Wattenhofer (2013), Rosenfeld (2014), A. K. Miller and LaViola (2014), Sapirshtein, Sompolinsky, and Zohar (2015), Göbel, Keeler, Krzesinski, and Taylor (2015), Lewenberg, Bachrach, Sompolinsky, Zohar, and Rosenschein (2015), Houy (2016), Cocco and Marchesi (2016), Solat and Potop-Butucaru (2016), Beccuti and Jaag (2017), Chiu and Koeppl (2017), Dimitri (2017), Aggarwal, Brennen, Lee, Santha, and Tomamichel (2018), L. Cong, Li, and Wang (2018), Hayes (2019), Easley, O'Hara, and Basu (2019), L. W. Cong, He, and Li (2019), and Wang et al (2019). The assumption that the mining process follows the Poisson distribution implies that the miners' probabilities of winning remain constant throughout the race (i.e., throughout the time that elapses between the moment at which a miner starts trying to find the next valid block and the moment at which any miner finds and broadcasts that valid block).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%