Our system is currently under heavy load due to increased usage. We're actively working on upgrades to improve performance. Thank you for your patience.
2004
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2184950
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Bank Runs and Investment Decisions Revisited

Abstract: We examine how the possibility of a bank run affects the deposit contract offered and the investment decisions made by a competitive bank. Cooper and Ross (1998) have shown that when the probability of a run is small, the bank will offer a contract that admits a bank-run equilibrium. We show that, in this case, the bank will chose to hold an amount of liquid reserves exactly equal to what withdrawal demand will be if a run does not occur. In other words, precautionary or "excess" liquidity will not be held. Th… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1

Citation Types

0
56
0

Year Published

2014
2014
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
6
1

Relationship

1
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 35 publications
(56 citation statements)
references
References 14 publications
(11 reference statements)
0
56
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Finally, the 28 See Van den Heuvel (2008) and Hanson, Kashyap and Stein (2011) for estimates of the liquidity premium for bank deposits. 29 In a model where the bank is funded only with deposits, Ennis and Keister (2006) show that shifting the asset mix towards more illiquid loans would result in a lower probability of being repaid given that a run occurs, which counterbalances the increase in credit extension when the probability of a run decreases. This does not need to be true in our model, because the increase in the credit extension is funded by more capital.…”
Section: Capital Requirementsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Finally, the 28 See Van den Heuvel (2008) and Hanson, Kashyap and Stein (2011) for estimates of the liquidity premium for bank deposits. 29 In a model where the bank is funded only with deposits, Ennis and Keister (2006) show that shifting the asset mix towards more illiquid loans would result in a lower probability of being repaid given that a run occurs, which counterbalances the increase in credit extension when the probability of a run decreases. This does not need to be true in our model, because the increase in the credit extension is funded by more capital.…”
Section: Capital Requirementsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…A fair amount of literature has focused on run-proof equilibria, which naturally restrict credit intermediation (see Cooper and Ross, 1998, Ennis and Keister, 2006, Diamond and Kashyap. 2016).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…9 A large value for n means that the aggregate demand for early withdrawals is high. In this case, it makes sense to devote less per capita resources to investment, reducing the e¤ective return for late withdrawals, spreading the additional early resources more thinly among the more numerous impatient depositors.…”
Section: Linear Technologymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Costly liquidation is prominently featured in the models of Cooper and Ross (1998) and Ennis and Keister (2006). In their environments, liquidating capital at date 1 reduces capital by more than one unit.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation