2014
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2471532
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Balance of Power and the Propensity of Conflict

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

0
10
0

Year Published

2019
2019
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
5

Relationship

0
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 5 publications
(10 citation statements)
references
References 88 publications
0
10
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Our study also relates to the experimental literature on bargaining in the shadow of conflict that examines, among other things, the effect of the asymmetry of conflict on bargaining outcomes (Hoffman and Spitzer, 1985;Kimbrough and Shremeta, 2014;Dechenaux et al, 2015;Herbst et al, 2017). Anbarci and Feltovich (2013) find that the negotiation strategies do not react to conflict asymmetries as much as the selfish sequentially rational theory would predict, but that QRE and otherregarding preferences can account for the observed patterns.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 58%
“…Our study also relates to the experimental literature on bargaining in the shadow of conflict that examines, among other things, the effect of the asymmetry of conflict on bargaining outcomes (Hoffman and Spitzer, 1985;Kimbrough and Shremeta, 2014;Dechenaux et al, 2015;Herbst et al, 2017). Anbarci and Feltovich (2013) find that the negotiation strategies do not react to conflict asymmetries as much as the selfish sequentially rational theory would predict, but that QRE and otherregarding preferences can account for the observed patterns.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 58%
“…However, we admittedly recognize that we develop our trade‐conflict model upon some simplifying assumptions. A potentially interesting extension of the model is to see how the conflict‐trade equilibrium in a two‐country framework is affected by strategic interventions of a third country or the possibility of mediation proposals (Herbst, Konrad, and Morath ) . Another possible extension is to see how differences in production technologies affect the trade equilibrium of two resource‐conflict nations and their optimal arming decisions.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Stressing the role of mediation proposals, Herbst, Konrad, and Morath () analyze how a disparity in fighting strengths between rivals affects the equilibrium outcome of bargaining under the shadow of conflict. The authors show experimentally that the possibility of fighting is not affected by power disparity with an exogenous mediation proposal.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Proposition 2: (i) A unique equilibrium of the Bargaining game exists in which both players participate for all parameter values. The equilibrium payoffs are described in (15).…”
Section: Solving the Bargaining Gamementioning
confidence: 99%
“…Although conflict occurred in the experiments more than predicted by theory, greater asymmetry did not induce more conflict. Kimbrough et al (2014) and Herbst et al (2017) allowed possibly asymmetric probabilities of winning in conflict to be endogenously determined. Kimbrough et al (2014) employed an ex ante random device instead of a bargaining game to resolve conflict and greater asymmetries induced some more conflict but not as much as expected theoretically.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%