2006
DOI: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2004.01.006
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Asymmetric benchmarking in compensation: Executives are rewarded for good luck but not penalized for bad

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

36
277
0
1

Year Published

2008
2008
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 403 publications
(314 citation statements)
references
References 21 publications
36
277
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…We conclude that delta incentives cause managers to have greater concern over avoiding the costs of financial distress than with the possibility of reducing the firm's credit costs in times of good performance. This pattern recalls the "asymmetric benchmarking" of CEO compensation incentives documented by Garvey and Milbourn (2006). CEOs' vega incentives are estimated as positive in both directions but without statistical significance.…”
Section: Interest Increasing and Interest Decreasing Slope Segmentssupporting
confidence: 56%
“…We conclude that delta incentives cause managers to have greater concern over avoiding the costs of financial distress than with the possibility of reducing the firm's credit costs in times of good performance. This pattern recalls the "asymmetric benchmarking" of CEO compensation incentives documented by Garvey and Milbourn (2006). CEOs' vega incentives are estimated as positive in both directions but without statistical significance.…”
Section: Interest Increasing and Interest Decreasing Slope Segmentssupporting
confidence: 56%
“…Greater agency problems in large …rms may necessitate higher equity incentives and thus more pay as a risk premium (Gayle and Miller, 2009). Our analyses in Sections 2.1.1 and 2.3.2 con…rm that …rm size is strongly positively related to both CEO pay levels and their e¤ective dollar ownership.…”
Section: Evidencementioning
confidence: 60%
“…An increase in …rm size can also raise the optimal level of CEO e¤ort if the marginal product of e¤ort increases with size (Himmelberg and Hubbard, 2000;Baker and Hall, 2004). Finally, moral hazard problems may be more severe in larger …rms, resulting in stronger incentives and greater disutility for CEOs as …rms grow (Gayle and Miller, 2009). …”
Section: Other Shareholder Value Explanationsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Another related strand in the executive compensation literature is benchmarking or relative performance evaluation; that is, indexing CEO pay to industry or market benchmarks (e.g., Jensen and Murphy, 1990;Gibbons and Murphy, 1990;Aggarwal and Samwick, 1999;Garvey and Milbourn, 2006). In theory, the compensation policy as an incentive mechanism, if working effectively, should pay for good performance and penalize for bad performance.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…As a result, due to the predominantly strong market years over the period starting from the early 1990s, the findings of such studies might be heavily influenced by pay for good performance and overlook penalty for bad performance, thereby leading to potentially biased inferences. For example, Garvey and Milbourn (2006) report asymmetric benchmarking in compensation so that executives are rewarded for good luck but not penalized for bad luck. Our study, by examining the executive compensation practices in the set of financially distressed firms and by comparing these firms to similar firms that are not financially distressed, concentrates on the situations where firms clearly under-perform the market and thus, one would expect that boards would find benchmarking relatively easy to implement.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%