The platform will undergo maintenance on Sep 14 at about 7:45 AM EST and will be unavailable for approximately 2 hours.
2007
DOI: 10.1016/j.geb.2006.10.014
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

An experimental study of truth-telling in a sender–receiver game

Abstract: A recent experimental study of Cai and Wang [Cai, H., Wang, J., 2006. Overcommunication in strategic information transmission games. Games Econ. Behav. 95, 384-394] on strategic information transmission reveals that subjects tend to transmit more information than predicted by the standard equilibrium analysis. To evidence that this overcommunication phenomenon can be explained in terms of a tension between normative social behavior and incentives for lying, we show in a simple sender-receiver game that subject… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
2

Citation Types

6
107
0

Year Published

2008
2008
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
8
1

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 196 publications
(115 citation statements)
references
References 22 publications
6
107
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Sutter's (2007) main concern is whether people who tell the truth in fact intend to deceive their partner; he does not run the control dictator games as Gneezy did and we do, and hence cannot speak to people's preferences over final outcomes. Sánchez-Pagés and Vorsatz (2007) suggest that truth-telling preferences can explain the behavior they find in a sender-receiver game. While our focus here is on the interaction of lying aversion and social preferences of the sender, they study the receiver's preferences to punish the sender for lying, and how this affects lying behavior.…”
Section: Related Literaturementioning
confidence: 98%
“…Sutter's (2007) main concern is whether people who tell the truth in fact intend to deceive their partner; he does not run the control dictator games as Gneezy did and we do, and hence cannot speak to people's preferences over final outcomes. Sánchez-Pagés and Vorsatz (2007) suggest that truth-telling preferences can explain the behavior they find in a sender-receiver game. While our focus here is on the interaction of lying aversion and social preferences of the sender, they study the receiver's preferences to punish the sender for lying, and how this affects lying behavior.…”
Section: Related Literaturementioning
confidence: 98%
“…See also Boles et al (2000), Crawford (2003), Brandts and Charness (2003), Croson et al (2003), Ellingsen and Johnnesson (2004), Cai and Wang (2006), Charness and Dufwenberg (2006), Sánchez-Pagés and Vorsatz (2007), Mazar and Ariely (2006), Mazar et al (2008), Dreber and Johannesson (2008), Sutter (2009), Lundquist et al (2009), Ellingsen et al (2009), Gino and Pierce (2009), Gino and Ayal (2011), and Gintis (2012). For a discussion of the social psychology literature on lies, see DePaulo et al (1996).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For example, Shalvi et al (2011) andFischbacher &Föllmi-Heusi (2013) find that subjects do not always lie to gain money, even when their doing so cannot be detected. Significantly less than "full" lying is also found in sender-receiver contexts (Gneezy, 2005;Hurkens & Kartik, 2009), bargaining games (Lundquist et al, 2009, and hold-up games (Ellingsen & Johannesson, 2004), with some studies finding evidence of lying aversion per se (Sánchez-Pagés & Vorsatz, 2007).…”
Section: Related Literature and Contributionsmentioning
confidence: 99%