2004
DOI: 10.1086/420968
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Agricultural Productivity Growth, Rural Economic Diversity, and Economic Reforms: India, 1970–2000

Abstract: JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.. The University of Chicago Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Economic Development and Cultural Change.

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

7
119
1
3

Year Published

2009
2009
2022
2022

Publication Types

Select...
5
4

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 196 publications
(130 citation statements)
references
References 4 publications
7
119
1
3
Order By: Relevance
“…On the other hand, the traded sector would not depend on local demand and would not be correlated with agricultural productivity via this route. Using a panel data set for a set of villages across India, Foster and Rosenzweig (2003) argue that "non-traded sectors are family businesses with few employees while factories are large employers and frequently employ workers from outside the village in which they are located." In a companion paper, they state that on average non-traded service enterprises consists of 2-3 workers.…”
Section: Empirical Strategymentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…On the other hand, the traded sector would not depend on local demand and would not be correlated with agricultural productivity via this route. Using a panel data set for a set of villages across India, Foster and Rosenzweig (2003) argue that "non-traded sectors are family businesses with few employees while factories are large employers and frequently employ workers from outside the village in which they are located." In a companion paper, they state that on average non-traded service enterprises consists of 2-3 workers.…”
Section: Empirical Strategymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This possibility was suggested by the work of Foster and Rosenzweig (2003). Their findings stem from a panel data set over the period collected by the National Council of Applied Economic Research (NCAER).…”
Section: Empirical Strategymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…As emphasized by Lanjouw and Lanjouw (2001), the main options available for the unemployed rural community in this scenario are either migration to urban areas or engagement in off-farm activities in rural areas. Actually, smallholder farmers in developing countries rarely rely on a full-time agricultural work; rather, they often maintain a portfolio of activities in which off-farm activities are an important contributions to their well-being (Barrett et al 2001;Foster and Rosenzweig 2004;Smith et al 2005;Wouterse and Taylor 2008;Lanjouw and Murgai 2009;Zezza et al 2009;Davis et al 2010;Haggblade et al 2010).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…How big is this growth-effect likely to be? In a careful study of a panel of thousands of households drawn from 240 villages spread over 15 of the biggest states, Foster and Rosenzweig (2004) found that per capita incomes rose by 70 percent over the period 1982-1999, implying an average annual growth rate of 3.1 percent. Much of this growth stemmed from increased earnings from non-agricultural activities, for which transport connections are important.…”
Section: Summing Upmentioning
confidence: 99%