2012
DOI: 10.1007/s11403-012-0100-y
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Agent-based financial markets and New Keynesian macroeconomics: a synthesis

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

0
48
0

Year Published

2014
2014
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
3
3
1

Relationship

1
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 54 publications
(48 citation statements)
references
References 54 publications
0
48
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Typical assumptions for possible channels which affect the real sector from within the financial one are, (1) the existence of wealth effects (Kontonikas and Montagnoli (2006), Bask (2011), Westerhoff (2012, Naimzada and Pireddu (2013)), (2) a collateral based cost effect (Lengnick and Wohltmann (2013)) or (3) a balance-sheet based leverage targeting effect (Scheffknecht and Geiger (2011)). Typical examples for channels going in the opposite direction are (1) a misperception effect (Kontonikas and Montagnoli (2006), Westerhoff (2012), DeGrauwe and Kaltwasser (2012), Lengnick and Wohltmann (2013), Naimzada and Pireddu (2013)), (2) a negative dependence on the (real) interest rate (Kontonikas and Montagnoli (2006)), or (3) a mixture of both (Bask (2011)).…”
Section: Microfounding An Extended Is-curvementioning
confidence: 99%
See 3 more Smart Citations
“…Typical assumptions for possible channels which affect the real sector from within the financial one are, (1) the existence of wealth effects (Kontonikas and Montagnoli (2006), Bask (2011), Westerhoff (2012, Naimzada and Pireddu (2013)), (2) a collateral based cost effect (Lengnick and Wohltmann (2013)) or (3) a balance-sheet based leverage targeting effect (Scheffknecht and Geiger (2011)). Typical examples for channels going in the opposite direction are (1) a misperception effect (Kontonikas and Montagnoli (2006), Westerhoff (2012), DeGrauwe and Kaltwasser (2012), Lengnick and Wohltmann (2013), Naimzada and Pireddu (2013)), (2) a negative dependence on the (real) interest rate (Kontonikas and Montagnoli (2006)), or (3) a mixture of both (Bask (2011)).…”
Section: Microfounding An Extended Is-curvementioning
confidence: 99%
“…Typical examples for channels going in the opposite direction are (1) a misperception effect (Kontonikas and Montagnoli (2006), Westerhoff (2012), DeGrauwe and Kaltwasser (2012), Lengnick and Wohltmann (2013), Naimzada and Pireddu (2013)), (2) a negative dependence on the (real) interest rate (Kontonikas and Montagnoli (2006)), or (3) a mixture of both (Bask (2011)). …”
Section: Microfounding An Extended Is-curvementioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…For instance, Lengnick and Wohltmann [27] combine a simple agent-based model of financial markets and a New Keynesian macroeconomic model with bounded rationality via two straightforward channels. They bring a macroeconomic model which enables the endogenous development of business cycles and stock price bubbles.…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%