2022
DOI: 10.1007/s11579-022-00324-6
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

A two-player portfolio tracking game

Abstract: We study the competition of two strategic agents for liquidity in the benchmark portfolio tracking setup of Bank et al. (Math Financial Economics 11(2):215–239 2017). Specifically, both agents track their own stochastic running trading targets while interacting through common aggregated temporary and permanent price impact à la Almgren and Chriss (J Risk 3:5–39 2001). The resulting stochastic linear quadratic differential game with terminal state constraints allows for a unique and explicitly available open-lo… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
2
1

Citation Types

0
8
0

Year Published

2022
2022
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
6

Relationship

0
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 6 publications
(8 citation statements)
references
References 32 publications
0
8
0
Order By: Relevance
“…More specifically, it tracks an “aim portfolio” (a constant multiple Maim$M_{aim}$ of the frictionless optimal holdings μt/γ$\mu _t/\gamma$) with a constant (relative) trading rate Mrate$M_{rate}$. This parallels results for single‐agent models (Gârleanu & Pedersen, 2016), a central planner (Section 4.1), or open‐loop equilibria (Voß, 2019; Casgrain and Jaimungal, 2020 or Section 4.2). However, the coefficients as well as the corresponding optimal value all depend on the form of the agents' strategic interaction.…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 54%
See 3 more Smart Citations
“…More specifically, it tracks an “aim portfolio” (a constant multiple Maim$M_{aim}$ of the frictionless optimal holdings μt/γ$\mu _t/\gamma$) with a constant (relative) trading rate Mrate$M_{rate}$. This parallels results for single‐agent models (Gârleanu & Pedersen, 2016), a central planner (Section 4.1), or open‐loop equilibria (Voß, 2019; Casgrain and Jaimungal, 2020 or Section 4.2). However, the coefficients as well as the corresponding optimal value all depend on the form of the agents' strategic interaction.…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 54%
“…To wit, each agent considers the others' feedback controls to be fixed, but takes into account how their own deviations from the equilibrium impact others' trading through their effect on the model's state variables 6. In the present context, single‐agent optimal trading rates (Gârleanu & Pedersen, 2016) and open‐loop Nash equilibria (Voß, 2019) are functions of the (exogenous) trading signal μt$\mu _t$ and the (endogenous) risky positions φt=(φt1,,φtN)$\varphi _t=(\varphi ^1_t,\ldots ,\varphi ^N_t)$ of the agents. We, therefore, naturally search for a closed‐loop equilibrium in the same class of strategies.…”
Section: Modelmentioning
confidence: 96%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…One of the main challenges in the area of finite population stochastic games is to derive explicitly the Nash equilibrium of the system. Motivating examples from mathematical finance include price impact games with competition for liquidity between agents [36,12,14,35,32], systemic risk games introduced by Carmona et al [9,10], Fouque and Zhang [17], as well as optimal investment problems studied in Lacker and Zariphopoulou [28], Lacker and Soret [27]. In various important extensions of the aforementioned models it turns out that the state variables of the players and their objective functionals naturally depend on the entire trajectory of the controls.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%