2005
DOI: 10.1016/j.geb.2004.09.013
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

A folk theorem for minority games

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
5

Citation Types

0
18
0

Year Published

2008
2008
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
4
2

Relationship

2
4

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 23 publications
(18 citation statements)
references
References 16 publications
0
18
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Notice that this is equivalent to announcing to each player her own reward at each time, but not the reward of the other players. Renault et al (2005) prove that an undiscounted folk theorem holds for this game, and characterize the set of uniform equilibrium payoffs, i.e. they show that any feasible payoff is an equilibrium payoff.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 96%
See 4 more Smart Citations
“…Notice that this is equivalent to announcing to each player her own reward at each time, but not the reward of the other players. Renault et al (2005) prove that an undiscounted folk theorem holds for this game, and characterize the set of uniform equilibrium payoffs, i.e. they show that any feasible payoff is an equilibrium payoff.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 96%
“…The players in the same room do not recognize each other, and between the stages only the current majority room is publicly announced, hence the game has imperfect public monitoring. An undiscounted version of this game was considered by Renault et al (2005), who proved a folk theorem. Here we consider a discounted version and a finitely repeated version of the game, and we strengthen our previous result by showing that the set of equilibrium payoffs Hausdorff-converges to the feasible set as either the discount factor goes to one or the number of repetition goes to infinity.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 3 more Smart Citations