1958
DOI: 10.1215/s0012-7094-58-02537-7
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

A class of simple games

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

2
92
0

Year Published

1994
1994
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
5
4

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 153 publications
(98 citation statements)
references
References 0 publications
2
92
0
Order By: Relevance
“…In this paper, we will look at the extension of the desirability relation for simple games [13] to the ternary voting game (or more generally for (3, 2) games) given in [24], wherein such an extension was denominated influence relation. In [24], it is proved that the influence relation fails to be transitive and cycles for players are possible.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In this paper, we will look at the extension of the desirability relation for simple games [13] to the ternary voting game (or more generally for (3, 2) games) given in [24], wherein such an extension was denominated influence relation. In [24], it is proved that the influence relation fails to be transitive and cycles for players are possible.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…(Isbell, [5]) Let (N, W) be a simple game, i and j be two voters. Player i is said to be more desirable than j, denoted by i j if the following two conditions are fulfilled:…”
Section: Complete Simple Gamesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…If j strictly dominates i (j W i), then j is said more desirable than i (Isbell, 1958). In a voting rule W, seat i is a seat with veto if for any S ∈ W , i ∈ S. Obviously a seat with veto dominates any other seat.…”
Section: Freixas and Puente (2003))mentioning
confidence: 99%