2000
DOI: 10.1007/s007800050008
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Efficient hedging: Cost versus shortfall risk

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

3
260
0
2

Year Published

2003
2003
2014
2014

Publication Types

Select...
4
4

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 276 publications
(265 citation statements)
references
References 15 publications
3
260
0
2
Order By: Relevance
“…A further possibility is to consider "coherent" measures of risk, introduced by Artzner et al (1999), and extended to a dynamic setting by and Cvitanià c and Karatzas (1999). One example of such a risk measure is provided by the "shortfall risk" minimisation of F ollmer and Leukert (2000). In general, the interaction between agents' preferences and option prices in incomplete markets is a fertile area for future research, and recent papers addressing this topic include Rouge and El Karoui (2000), Barrieu and El Karoui (2002) and Musiela and Zariphopoulou (2001).…”
Section: Conclusion and Suggestionsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…A further possibility is to consider "coherent" measures of risk, introduced by Artzner et al (1999), and extended to a dynamic setting by and Cvitanià c and Karatzas (1999). One example of such a risk measure is provided by the "shortfall risk" minimisation of F ollmer and Leukert (2000). In general, the interaction between agents' preferences and option prices in incomplete markets is a fertile area for future research, and recent papers addressing this topic include Rouge and El Karoui (2000), Barrieu and El Karoui (2002) and Musiela and Zariphopoulou (2001).…”
Section: Conclusion and Suggestionsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…As a consequence, we decided to follow a "dual" approach (with techniques similar to those in [3]), based on the fact that the problem min α E S0,V0 {(H(S N )−V α N ) + } has the same solution as the "static" problem min X∈X E S0 H(S N )− X , where X := {X | X ≤ H(S N ) (a.s.), E * {X} ≤ V 0 } is the set of the so-called modified contingent claims, i.e., all the claims less than H(S N ) which can be replicated with initial capital (less than or equal to) V 0 . It is then possible to show that the optimal solution of the static problem min X∈X E S0 H(S N ) − X is given by the modified contingent claim X * := H(S N ) − I c * dP * dP , with I := ( ) −1 and c * > 0 chosen in such a way that E * {X * } = V 0 .…”
Section: Risk Averse Investormentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The analysis of this question is implicitly included in the works of Föllmer and Leukert ( [15], [16]) in great generality (cf. [29] in a discrete-time framework).…”
Section: Portfolio Theory and The Relevance Of Benchmarksmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This expected return is always non-negative (cf. (16)) since the expectation is taken under the measure P π (1) for which the portfolio (π(1) k ) k≥1 is the growth optimal strategy. The expected return is zero if and only if the proportions π(1) and π(2) coincide (cf.…”
Section: Propositionmentioning
confidence: 99%