1994
DOI: 10.1016/0047-2727(94)90056-6
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Costs of monitoring and corporate taxation

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
22
0

Year Published

1998
1998
2014
2014

Publication Types

Select...
5
2

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 23 publications
(22 citation statements)
references
References 24 publications
0
22
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Notice that under the accounting standards followed by …rms investing in both the United States and the United Kingdom, provision for deferred taxes are measured on the di¤erence between accounting and tax depreciation, whereas the above de…nition of the period t provision for deferred taxes assumes that economic depreciation equals accounting depreciation. We retain this assumption on that basis that it is consistent with the standard conventions in the established literature on tax policy and …nancial constraints -see previously cited papers by Boadway and Bruce (1979), Södersten (1994 and1995), King (1974), Sørensen (1995) -and also taking into account the fact that over the past 20 years accounting standards followed by United States and United Kingdom companies have increased their ‡exibility in order to align accounting depreciation to economic depreciation. Indeed, the IAS 16 (International GAAP 2010) does not prescribe any speci…c method and/or rate of depreciation for accounting purposes, as it requires the depreciation charge to re ‡ect the pattern of consumption of the bene…ts the assets brings over its useful life, which is essentially consistent with economic depreciation.…”
Section: Constrained Emtrmentioning
confidence: 79%
“…Notice that under the accounting standards followed by …rms investing in both the United States and the United Kingdom, provision for deferred taxes are measured on the di¤erence between accounting and tax depreciation, whereas the above de…nition of the period t provision for deferred taxes assumes that economic depreciation equals accounting depreciation. We retain this assumption on that basis that it is consistent with the standard conventions in the established literature on tax policy and …nancial constraints -see previously cited papers by Boadway and Bruce (1979), Södersten (1994 and1995), King (1974), Sørensen (1995) -and also taking into account the fact that over the past 20 years accounting standards followed by United States and United Kingdom companies have increased their ‡exibility in order to align accounting depreciation to economic depreciation. Indeed, the IAS 16 (International GAAP 2010) does not prescribe any speci…c method and/or rate of depreciation for accounting purposes, as it requires the depreciation charge to re ‡ect the pattern of consumption of the bene…ts the assets brings over its useful life, which is essentially consistent with economic depreciation.…”
Section: Constrained Emtrmentioning
confidence: 79%
“…An early exception is found in Kanniainen and Södersten (1994) who analyze the impact of bank monitoring on the response of firms to corporate taxes. They take the view that monitoring perfectly solves any conflict between shareholders and the management; hence, agency problems that result in diverging investment incentives are effectively absent in their analysis.…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…α * * = α * (m * * , z) and m * * = m * (α * * ). 33 With local stability of the Nash equilibrium, the sign of the change in α * * in response to a hike in z follows from ∂α * (m, z)/∂z and the sign of the change in m * * from dm * (α)/dα, implying that the change ∂α * (m, z)/∂m does not influence the qualitative changes in α * * and m * * . 34 Intuitively, a rise in z has a direct effect on α which changes the monitoring intensity as implied by the slope of the bank's best response.…”
Section: Investment Policy Incentive Contracts and Monitoringmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Why firms do not fully use their tax allowance possibilities and how this would affect the corporate tax paid on a marginal investment is discussed in e.g. Bergström and Södersten (1984) and Kanniainen and Södersten (1994 Our results show close similarities with Södersten's calculations for occasional years from 1960 and on, as reported in Henrekson (1996) and Henrekson and Johansson (2009). But differences can be seen if one compares with Södersten and Lindhe's (1983) results, which is explained by the fact that their results include three different ownership categories (besides households, also insurance companies and tax-exempted institutions).…”
Section: General Frameworkmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…65 When funds are released, the IF system can be characterized as a general profit subsidy which can be interpreted as a general deduction of the statutory tax rate. 66 According to Agell et al (1995, p. 116), a reasonable assumption about the IF system is that it could reduce the corporate tax rate with about 15 percentage points, as described in section 3.2. This may reduce the METR with about ten percentage points, see Figure B2.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%